Monday, September 23, 2019

Actions to take when banks are faced with liquidity problems, rationale for such actions and risks involved


Introduction
In a case where one of the leading banks in the economy is facing liquidity issues, various risks are involved with the main one being the escalation of the problem to affect the entire financial system. Liquidity problems in banking institutions are in most cases a signal that various things may be wrong or are bound to go wrong (Sullivan, 2003). It is therefore imperative that an urgent inquiry be conducted to establish the extent of the problem. However, since the inquiry could take a while for a comprehensive finding to be reported, it is important that immediate intervention be conducted. Financial markets are often volatile and should information spread among depositors and creditors that the bank is likely to fail; the problem would only escalate (Jackson, 2009; Quintyn and Taylor, 2004). One of options that the bank could take would be to conduct a bailout where the central bank provides the struggling bank with funds to meet their short term obligations. The central bank could also guarantee the short term liabilities of the company in order to lessen the pressure on their cash flows. In the long term, it is important to re-examine the causes of the liquidity crunch and come up with corrective measures (Centre for Economic Policy Research, 2010; Iyade, 2006). For instance, the regulations for lending could allow for excessive subprime lending hence leading to massive defaults. This paper considers the situation of the central bank governor who is faced with a liquidity crunch in one of the largest banks in the economy. It evaluates the rationale for taking action, examines the options available for action and the impact of such options when implemented.   

Risks of inaction
For action to be deemed as necessary, it is important to understand the risks involved and the likely impact of inaction. To begin with, the situation could lead to the destabilisation of the financial system if left unattended. Other problems that could arise if the situation is not swiftly resolved are asset management problems, loan freeze and the zombie lending problem. The cardinal responsibility of the central bank is to protect the depositors, ensure that the relationship between lender and borrower is stabilised, and to ensure that there are no disruptions in the banking functions in the economy (Aikins, 2009; Benson and Kaufman, 1996).

The financial system plays a key role in market economies. It facilitates transactions and in many cases acts as a crucial driver of economic growth. In most cases, the stability of the financial system hinges on the confidence that the market have in the main industry player- the mainstream banks (Jackson, 2009). In this case, the biggest bank in the economy is facing liquidity problems. It implies that a deterioration of the situation would not only lower the market confidence in the concerned bank alone, but also in the entire financial system. A wavering confidence in the financial system would lead to all persons having deposits in banks moving to withdraw them in fear of the system collapsing and having them lose their savings (Bank of England, 2011). The situation in the bank is therefore likely to affect the whole economy and it therefore calls for swift intervention.

If the situation is allowed to persist, the bank may be forced to freeze loans. Such a move would create a credit crunch in the economy in view of the fact that this is the largest bank in the economy. The provision of loans drives economic activities with most potent businesses often in need of short term and long term loans to advance their organisational goals (Chartered Institute of Management Accountants, 2010; Dewatripoint and Freixas, 2012). A freeze would therefore have a massive impact on the ordinary economic life with many organisations paralysed by lack of working capital. The central bank therefore needs to take action and ensure that economic activity in the economy is not disrupted by intervening in the situation as quickly as possible.   

Evaluation of bailouts and other interventions
The interventions to be taken should both be long term and short term. In the short term, the concern should be to resolve the liquidity issue and ensure that customers can access their funds without disruption. Other crucial banking activities such as lending should go on uninterrupted due to their contribution to the economic welfare of the country (Deringer, 2011). In the longer term, issues of regulation and correction of faults in the system that could have led to the situation should be examined and remedied accordingly. The systems could either be related to the regulatory frameworks or lack of effective supervision of the players in the financial services industry.

In bailouts, the central bank allocates funds to the ailing banks to enable them overcome their immediate liquidity problems (Stone, Fujita and Ishi, 2011). It is important that an analysis be conducted to determine the level of bailout needed. Excess expenditure of the bailout could prove to be wasteful while inadequate intervention could be counter-productive (Stone, Fujita and Ishi, 2011). The central bank should buy time for conducting a thorough analysis by providing smaller proportions of bailout while need is being assessed. Bailouts have attracted a fair share of controversy in the recent past with critics taking the view that the tax payer was in such cases forced to shoulder the bill for inefficient bank managers (New, 2010). This is especially the case where the bailouts are conducted without an insistence on the restructuring of the shareholding in such organisations. Bailouts have also been touted as a source of motivation for bank managers to pursue aggressive and relatively reckless approaches in their lending practices (The Treasury Committee, 2011). They allow shareholders to shift risk to the tax payer. The knowledge that the bank would be saved if things went wrong takes away the motivation for such managers to be vigilant in risk assessment and vetting of borrowers. However, it is important to appreciate the fact that bailouts are done to protect the very same tax payers and to ensure that economic activity is stabilised. Recklessness can be prevented by ensuring that bailouts are accompanied by restructuring where initial equity holders lose their stake partially or completely (Treasury Committee, 2011).

An alternative to the bailouts option could be the use of guarantees. By providing guarantees, the central bank lessens the pressure on the cash-flow of the banks (Norris, 2011). Creditors can lend to the bank in full awareness of the fact that their debts will certainly get paid. The complication with this option is that it may not solve the immediate liquidity problem. However, it could be a good option to pursue in the mid-term. It can also be pursued where the amount allowable to provide for bailout may be limited. Some of the factors that could lead to the inability of the central bank to give the desired amounts in a bailout could include limits by legislation, the budget deficits in the government and a host of other factors (Beck and Wieland, 2008). This option could be used to subsidise bailouts where the former is insufficient.

The longer term approaches deal with regulation: diagnosis of the causes of a crisis and introduction of intervention to ensure that the situation does not arise again. One of the causes could be the provision for low reserve ratios where banks are allowed to retain very little funds and this would lead to a situation where there are problems in a situation where withdrawals by depositors surge significantly (Morgan, 2009). In most cases, the reserve ratios would be enough to cater for withdrawal needs. However, poor compliance could see banks lend more than they should and this could result in such a situation. The system could also be affected by the practice of subprime lending where banks offer credit to borrowers with poor credit ratings. This could lead to massive loan defaults which could lead to the situation described above. It is in fact known that the global economic recession was largely caused by subprime lending which resulted in massive defaults (Morgan, 2009).

The processes involved in underwriting property or the determination of the value of assets used as collateral can also be a problem. This problem came to the fore in the global recession where the underwriting processes were corrupted. Under corrupted systems, people could take loans based on exaggerated value of assets and this made it difficult for banks to recover their funds from defaulters (Almeida, Fry and Goodhart, 1999). These are processes within the financial services sector that the central bank can influence and ensure that timely interventions are made. A review of financial processes leading up to the determination of value of property and credit worthiness of individuals should be done. For instance, infrastructure allowing for information sharing among banks on credit record of borrowers could help in reducing the risk of massive defaults.

Expected outcome of actions taken and possible risks 
A bailout would be expected to help the organisation work its way out of liquidity crunch and resume normal activity (Almeida, Fry and Goodhart, 1999; Goodhart and Schoenmaker, 1995). It is supposed to ensure that depositors can access their funds without fail with the banks also being able to advance loans to creditors. It is expected that the bailout funds would be used with care bearing in mind the poor practices that may have landed the bank in question in its current predicament (Neuenkirch, 2012). Bailouts when used alone do not go far enough. They fail to intervene in the weaknesses in the management practises and this implies that even the bailout funds could be mismanaged with the banking institution in question landing back into problems (Dombalagian, 2010; Morgan, 2009). In many cases, the bailout funds are not enough to raise the capital levels needed by the banks. The banks may therefore continue to freeze lending in order to raise such levels. This could beat the very purpose of such bailouts. Other practices such as zombie lending could continue despite the bailout and the central bank must remain aware of such possibilities. Intervention through bailout could also make things worse where the newly invigorated bank may seek to return to vibrancy by lending funds to parties that would not have qualified under normal circumstances (Lessiter, Bisping and Horton, 2010). In this case, the availability of a bailout constitutes part of the problem.

The regulation approach is very good in assuring the stability of the financial systems. However, they tend to be long term approaches. The immediate concern among banks facing liquidity issues is the need to ensure that the banking activities are not interrupted and that the depositors are able to access their money at any point (Donato, 2011; Li, 2007). Regulation, when used alone, could be too late in that there may be no financial system to regulate by the time the interventions are made since the damage to the market confidence would have already been done.

Enhancing the effectiveness of the interventions: lessons from the global recession
There are many lessons that could be learnt from the global financial crisis where the financial systems in most economies in the developed world were on the verge of collapsing. Governments allocated substantial budgetary allocations towards the bailout of banks where funds would be issued to banks to overcome their liquidity problems and resume their crucial role in driving economic activity (Donato, 2011a). These quick interventions led to the resumption of economic activity and the ending of the recession. In fact, it must be appreciated that whereas the economic recession was larger than the great depression, interventions were made to ensure that it was ended in a much shorter time span (Ibanez, Jimenez and Garaizar, 2011). The bailout by governments was accompanied by a focus on the financial systems. Practices that had led to the situation were outlawed with other unregulated practices brought under regulation. For instance, focus in the UK shifted to the shadow banking sector and how the sector could be regulated to ensure enhanced stability in the financial system (Ibanez, Jimenez and Garaizar, 2011). Standardised ways of credit rating were also introduced to ensure accurate pricing of risk. There was also a reversal of the approach to regulation that had earlier emphasised self regulation where industry bodies would ensure compliance (Ezeoha, 2011). This important function was taken back to the relevant government agency to ensure that all loopholes that could lead to liquidity problems were sealed.

This is the approach that the central bank should take in this case. There should be a bailout to bring reprieve in the short term followed by rigorous system checks to determine the cause of the flaws and ensure that legislation is introduced to deal with any weaknesses found.


Conclusion and recommendations 
The stability of the financial system should be the main concern of the central bank. This stability is for the most part driven by the confidence that consumers have in the system. Depositors need to have confidence that the money they keep in banks is safe and available to them at will. Market players also need to have confidence that normal banking practices will remain stable and that would inform their approach to business (Li, 2007). In this case the largest bank in the economy is faced with liquidity problems where it is not able to meet its obligations to depositors. This is likely to affect the entire financial system and therefore warrants immediate intervention.

The most available tool for intervention is the use of a bailout. The central bank should provide the organisation with the funds needed to ensure that banking activities are stabilised. This bailout should be enough to return the company to normalcy with any deficits catered for by providing guarantees aimed at making it easy for the bank to obtain products and services from creditors. However, the bailout should be accompanied by a systems audit to determine the causes of the crisis and come up with ways of ensuring no recurrence in future.

To ensure that the bank and other banks in the market remain vigilant in their approaches, the bailout should be provided with some implications on the ownership and management structure of the organisation where the initial equity holders may partially lose their stake in the organisation. Such an approach would help in motivating the directors and management of the banks to remain vigilant in their risk management approaches to ensure that they do not put the financial system at risk in the future. 

The appropriate action to be taken would therefore be to mix an appropriate bailout with the institution of a corrective mechanism to institute stability in the bank and in the entire financial system.


References
Aikins, S.K. 2009. Global Financial Crisis and the Government Intervention: A case for effective regulatory governance. (Online) Available at: http://www.idt.unisg.ch/org/idt/ipmr.nsf/0/3677d9fbcd8a5cbfc1257671002a26b7/$FILE/Aikins_IPMR_Volume%2010_Issue%202.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Almeida, A., Fry, M.J., Goodhart, C.A.E., 1999. Central banking in developing countries: objectives, activities, and independence. New York: Routledge
Bank of England, 2011. Financial Stability Report. (Online) Available at: http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2011/fsrfull1106.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Beck, G.W., Wieland, V., 2008. Central bank misperceptions and the role of money in interest-rate rules. Journal of Monetary Studies, pp. S1-S17
Benson, G.J., Kaufman, G.G., 1996. The appropriate role of bank regulation. The Economic Journal, 106(May), 688-697
Centre for Economic Policy Research, 2010. Bailing out Banks: Reconciling stability and competition. (Online) Available at: http://www.cepr.org/pubs/other/Bailing_out_the_banks.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Chartered Institute of Management Accountants, 2010. The Global Banking Sector: Current Issues. (Online) Available at: http://e-finanse.com/RaportyCIMA/5.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Deringer, F.B., 2011. Bank of the Future: UK Financial Regulation. (Online) Available at: http://www.freshfields.com/publications/pdfs/2011/may11/30345.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Dewatripoint, M., Freixas, X., 2012. Bank resolution: a framework for the assessment of regulatory intervention. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 27(3), pp. 411-436
Dombalagian, O., 2010. Requiem for the Bulge Bracket: Revisiting Investment Bank Regulation. Indiana Law Journal, 85(3), pp. 777-849
Donato, M., 2011a. Exploring governance of the new European Banking Authority: a case of Harmonisation? Journal of Financial Stability. 7(4), pp. 204-214
Donato, M.M 2011. Measuring the financial supervision architectures and the role of central banks. Journal of Financial Transformation. 32, pp.9-14
Ezeoha, A.E., 2011. Banking consolidation, credit crisis and asset quality in a fragile banking system: Some evidence from Nigeria. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance, 19(1), pp. 33-44
Goodhart, C., Schoenmaker, D., 1995. Should the functions of monetary policy and banking supervision be separated, Oxford Economic Papers, 47(4), pp. 539-560
Ibanez, J.W., Jimenez, I., Garaizar, N., 2011. Grabbing vs Helping- Banking Supervision Dilemma: A global approach enhanced banking law compliance. Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation, 26(3), pp. 119-128
Iyade, A.I., 2006. The impact of regulation and supervision on the activities of banks in Nigeria (Online) Available at: http://www.stclements.edu/grad/gradiyad.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Jackson, J.K., 2009. The Financial crisis: impact on and response by the European Union. (Online) Available at: http://fpc.state.gov/documents/organization/127015.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Lassiter, J., Bisping, T.O., Horton, J., 2010. Central banking in transition economies: Estonia and Belarus. International Journal of Commerce and Management, 20(4), pp. 331-338
Li, T., 2007. Banking regulation around the world patterns, determinants and impact. Journal of Emerging Market Finance, 6(1), pp. 61-122
Morgan, J.,  2009. The limits of central bank policy: economic crisis and the challenge of effective solutions. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33(4), pp. 581-608
Neuenkirch, M., 2012. Managing financial market expectations: the role of central bank in transparency and central bank communication, European Journal of Political Economy, 28(1), pp. 1-13
New, T., 2010. New York Times-Major Parts of the Financial Regulation Overhaul-May 2010. The New York Times. (Online) Available at: http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2010/05/20/business/20100520-regulation-graphic.html (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Norris, F., 2011. Crisis Is Over, but Where’s the Fix? New York Times. (Online) Available at: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/03/11/business/economy/11norris.html (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Quintyn, M., Taylor, M.W., 2004. Should financial sector regulators be independent? Economic Issues, 32 (Online) Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/issues/issues32/index.htm (Accessed 15 April 2012)
Stone, M., Fujita, k., Ishi, K., 2011. Unconventional Behaviour by Central Banks. Finance & Development, 48 (3), pp. 21-42
Sullivan, A., 2003. Economics : principles in action. Needham, Mass: Prentice Hall
The Treasury Committee, 2011. Financial Regulation: a preliminary consideration of the government’s proposals. (Online) Available at: http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201011/cmselect/cmtreasy/430/430i.pdf (Accessed 15 April 2012)

No comments:

Post a Comment

The Slaughtered and the Survivors: Collaboration Between Social Economy Organizations as a Key to Success in Times of Financial Crisis

CITATION López-Arceiz, F., Bellostas, A., & Rivera-Torres, M. (2017). The Slaughtered and the Survivors: Collaboration Between Social ...